RBA Cools Arder On Interest Rate Rises

Speaking at CEDA today, RBA Deputy Governor Guy Debelle seemed to be intent on hosing down expectations of interest rate rises (in stark contrast to the RBA minutes earlier this week). He suggests that even if the Fed continues to lift their benchmark rate, it does not automatically follow we will see a rise here in Australia.

The neutral interest rate provides a benchmark for assessing the current stance of monetary policy. If the real policy rate – that is, the cash rate less inflation expectations – is below the neutral rate, then monetary policy is exerting an expansionary influence on the economy. If the real policy rate is above the neutral rate, then monetary policy is exerting a contractionary influence on the economy. The neutral rate is often associated with the turn of the 20th century Swedish economist Knut Wicksell and was picked up by Keynes. The previous Governor Glenn Stevens discussed the neutral rate in the Australian context more than a decade ago.

There was a discussion of the neutral rate at the most recent Board meeting, as detailed in the minutes of the meeting released earlier this week. No significance should be read into the fact the neutral rate was discussed at this particular meeting. Most meetings, the Board allocates some time to discussing a policy-relevant issue in more detail, and on this occasion it was the neutral rate.

The neutral interest rate aligns the amount of saving and investment in the economy at a level that is consistent with full employment and stable inflation. That is, the neutral rate is where the policy rate would settle down in the medium term when the goals of monetary policy are being achieved. Accordingly, most explanations of the neutral interest rate start with the factors that influence saving or investment. Developments that increase saving will tend to lower the neutral interest rate; developments that increase investment will tend to raise the neutral interest rate.

There are three main factors that, in my view, affect the neutral rate in Australia:

  • the economy’s potential growth rate
  • the degree of risk aversion
  • international factors.

One of the major determinants of the neutral interest rate is the economy’s potential growth rate. In an economy with a high potential growth rate, because it has strong productivity or population growth, the expectation of increased future demand provides a strong incentive for firms to invest and the prospect of higher real incomes reduces the incentives of households to save. Both of these forces will tend to raise the neutral interest rate. The economy’s potential growth rate tends to evolve quite slowly, and hence we should expect the neutral interest rate also to change only very gradually as a result of this influence.

Another influence on the neutral rate is the risk appetite of firms and households and the way risk has been priced into market interest rates. This influence can move rapidly. When risk aversion rises, firms require more compensation to make long-term investments with an uncertain return. At the same time, the increased risk aversion will cause households to save more. This lowers the neutral interest rate, as any given level of the policy rate is less expansionary because of the increased risk aversion. If there is an increase in risk aversion, it is also likely that there will be a widening in the spreads between the policy rate and market interest rates that determine the behaviour of households and firms. A given market interest rate will correspond to a lower policy rate if spreads widen. This will further lower the neutral interest rate.

Finally, in an open economy, where capital can move reasonably freely across borders, global interest rates will also influence domestic interest rates. This means that trends in overseas productivity growth, demographics and risk appetite will affect the neutral interest rate in Australia.

So how do we calculate the neutral interest rate? It is not directly observable. There are a number of different ways of estimating it from the behaviour of market interest rates and other economic variables. The shaded area in Graph 4 shows a range of plausible estimates for the neutral real interest rate obtained using a number of different approaches. As you can see, there is a reasonable amount of uncertainty about the exact level of the neutral rate.

Graph 4 also shows the (ex post) real cash rate calculated by deducting the trimmed mean inflation rate from the cash rate. When the real cash rate is above the neutral rate, the monetary policy stance is contractionary. When it is below, the stance is expansionary. As you look at the graph, you can see that this lines up with most assessments of the stance of monetary policy over the past 25 years. It suggests that monetary policy was clearly expansionary in the early 2000s, in 2008 and for the past five years or so.

Graph 4
Graph 4: Neutral Interest Rate

 

The estimates of the neutral rate suggest that it was fairly stable for much of the 1990s up until 2007. In Glenn Stevens’ speech that I mentioned earlier, he noted that the neutral real cash rate at the time (2004) was probably somewhere between 2½ per cent and 3¾ per cent. This is consistent with the estimates shown here.

The graph shows a clear step down in all the estimates of the neutral rate in 2007/08 and that it has probably drifted lower since. It suggests that Australia’s neutral interest rate is currently around 150 basis points lower now than in 2007. This decline can largely be accounted for by a slowdown in potential growth and an increase in risk aversion.

The Bank estimates that Australia’s long-run potential growth rate has declined by around ½ percentage point from the mid 1990s. Part of the decline reflects slower labour force growth. The rest of the decline reflects a slowdown in trend productivity growth, which is common to many advanced economies. This slowdown in potential growth has probably translated about one-for-one into a decline in the neutral rate, though the decline has been gradual.

The sharper decline in the neutral rate in 2007/08 can be most easily related to the sharp increase in risk aversion with the onset of the financial crisis. This increased risk aversion probably accounts for most of the large fall in estimated neutral interest rates in Australia and abroad that occurred at this time. This heightened risk aversion has also contributed to an increase in spreads between the cash rate and market interest rates, which should have a roughly one-for-one effect on the neutral interest rate.

At the same time, increased risk aversion means that companies are investing less than one would expect given financing conditions and the economic outlook. Households are less willing than in the past to borrow in order to fund consumption. Although these effects are hard to quantify, they would both lower the neutral interest rate.

To return to a global perspective, Graph 5 compares the average estimate of the neutral interest rate for Australia to a range of international estimates. On average, the neutral interest rate estimates for Australia are similar to those of the United Kingdom and Canada, but higher than those for the United States and the euro area.

As is the case for Australia, estimates of neutral interest rates in other developed economies were fairly stable until around the mid 2000s and have fallen since then. The decline in the neutral rate was particularly sharp in 2007/08 and, again, most likely reflects the increase in risk aversion at the onset of the financial crisis.

Graph 5
Graph 5: Global Neutral Interest Rates

 

Because trends in determinants of the neutral interest rate, such as productivity growth and risk appetite, tend to be highly correlated across advanced economies, it is hard to distinguish between international influences and domestic influences. But it is very likely that global factors have contributed to a decline in Australia’s neutral policy rate.

So in short, the policy rate in Australia is low because the neutral rate is lower than it used to be as a result of both international and domestic developments. This means that the current (nominal) cash rate setting of 1½ per cent today is not as expansionary as a cash rate of 1½ per cent would have been in the 1990s or the first half of the 2000s.

Looking ahead, the neutral policy rate both here in Australia as well as in other advanced economies is likely to remain lower than it was in the past. It is plausible that the degree of risk aversion might abate in time, which would see the neutral rate rise from its current low level. But other developments contributing to the lower neutral rates, particularly lower potential growth rates, could be more permanent.

 

Author: Martin North

Martin North is the Principal of Digital Finance Analytics

Leave a Reply